|

A Classical Liberal from Venezuela: Emilio Pacheco

Hannes Gissurarson honors Emilio Pacheco

The surroundings could not be more appropriate. We are overlooking Vienna from the 20th floor of the Ringturm, the highest building in the city after the cathedral, Stephansdom. Tonight we are celebrating the Hayek Lifetime Achievement Award, given out annually by the Hayek Institute and the Austrian Economics Center. Austrian-born Friedrich August von Hayek was, I believe, the modern thinker who provided the most cogent and plausible defence of Western civilisation. The question he posed was: How can we accomplish so much when we, as individuals, know so little? Briefly, his answer was: Because we can utilise the knowledge other people possess, and this we do through the price mechanism across places, in the international free market, and through traditions and practices across times. A well-functioning, progressive society is about the acquisition, transmission and utilisation of knowledge.

In his works, Hayek gives an account not only of individual reason, but also of collective reason, our accumulated cultural capital. Hayek’s theory of knowledge is more than a fascinating and powerful research programme in the social sciences: it also offers guidance to policy makers. Their main task should be to remove hindrances to the mutual adjustment of individual agents, to facilitate coordination without commands. For example, income distribution is not about a mother dividing up a cake between her children; it is rather an indispensable device providing us with information on how we can best utilise and develop our individual abilities and special talents for the benefit not only of ourselves but also of others. Damaging this device by enforced redistribution amounts to distorting and diverting the free flow of information; it is like removing road signals.

MG 2829 scaled

Previous Winners

Previous winners of the Hayek Lifetime Achievement Award include Peruvian novelist Mario Vargas Llosa, the 2010 Nobel Laureate in Literature, Scottish historian Niall Ferguson, formerly at Oxford and Harvard and now at the Hoover Institution in California, prolific American economic historian Deirdre McCloskey, successful American entrepreneur Peter Thiel, and influential American economist Arthur Laffer, after whom the Laffer Curve is named. Last year I had the pleasure to give a speech here in Vienna in honour of the Montenegrin economist and educationalist Veselin Vukotic who won the award for his tireless efforts to improve the economic conditions of his small and beautiful country, guided by the Austrian School of Economics to which Hayek belonged.

Hayek Lifetime Achievement Awardee Photos 2021

Emilio Pacheco

This year, I am happy to say, the Award goes to an old friend, Dr. Emilio Pacheco. He was born in March 1953 in Venezuela so he is only a month younger than me. In 1975, he graduated with a BA in Social Sciences from the Catholic University André Bello in his native country. Soon thereafter, he and his wife Isabel moved to England where in 1980 he completed an MA in intellectual history at the University of Sussex. After that, he came to Oxford where he studied politics at St. Anthony’s, and it was at Oxford that we became friends. I was there from 1981 to 1985. Emilio and Isabel stayed in Oxford until 1986 when Emilio graduated with a D.Phil. in Politics, and it was in Oxford that their older daughter Isabella spent her first years. They have a younger daughter, Iñez, and five grandchildren, Margot, Josefina, Agnes, Carmen and Oscar.

MG 2637 scaled

Hayek in Oxford

At Oxford, Emilio and I were both liberals in the classical (and not the contemporary American) sense, with me perhaps being more conservative than him. He was then as now a quiet, thoughtful, erudite scholar. We were both very interested in Hayek’s ideas. I had first met Hayek in 1980 when he came to Iceland and gave two lectures, and one of our teachers at Oxford, Dr. John Gray of Jesus College, shared our interest in Hayek and was himself working on a book on him. In the spring of 1983, Hayek visited us in Oxford, and we took him to a Chinese restaurant, Xian on Banbury Road. Over dinner, we had a long and fruitful discussion with him, not least about the two most prominent schools of free market economics, the Chicago School of Frank H. Knight, Milton Friedman, George J. Stigler, and Gary S. Becker, and the Austrian School of Hayek himself, Carl Menger, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, Ludwig von Mises and to some extent Joseph Schumpeter.

At the end of the dinner, we asked Hayek whether he would gave us permission to use his name because we wanted to found a Hayek Society at Oxford for regular discussions about liberal principles and problems. Hayek said: ‘Of course I am delighted that young people are interested in my ideas. But if I am to give you permission to use my name, you have in return to make a promise to me, for your own good. Do not become Hayekians. I have noticed that the Marxists are much worse than Marx and that the Keynesians are much worse than Keynes. You have to maintain a criticial distance from people. It is the ideas that matter. They are indeed much more powerful in the long run than special interests.’

17.15Hayek.Pacheco.1985

Photo courtesy of Prof. Gissurarson

The Oxford Hayek Society

We made the promise that Hayek wanted, although I am not sure that all of us were able to fulfil it. Speaking for myself, I am in agreement with Hayek on most issues, except perhaps on nationalism. It left an indelible mark on Hayek that he had witnessed the collapse of the multi-national Danubian Empire of the Habsburgs which had been a vast free trade zone, sharing a sound and stable currency. He blamed its collapse on nationalism whereas I would argue for national sovereignty, but certainly in combination with free trade and an international competitive market. In other words, economic integration does not necessarily presuppose political integration.

In another sense we followed Hayek’s admonition because we were not afraid of inviting critics of classical liberalism to speak at our biweekly meetings during terms. They included communist philosopher Gerry Cohen, always witty and sharp, market socialist David Miller, widely read and judicious, and social democrat Raymond Plant, who was interested in the somewhat esoteric subject what it was that Hegel and Hayek had in common. Most of our speakers were however, I confess, broadly sympathetic to Hayek’s classical liberalism. Indeed, three of them published books on Hayek, Jeremy Shearmur (who had for a while been Karl Popper’s research assistant), Norman Barry and John Gray. After the meetings we took the speaker of the day out for dinner, usually at Michel’s Brasserie in Little Clarendon Street. This was often the most enjoyable and stimulating part of the event.

The Hayek Society at

Photo courtesy of Prof. Gissurarson

A Dinner in London

We kept in touch with Hayek, and in the spring of 1985 he told us that he would be in London one day and that we could meet. I wrote to Leonard Liggio who was in charge of the Hayek Fund which was supposed to encourage liberal scholarship, and he gave us a small grant which enabled us to invite Hayek to dinner at the Ritz in London. There were five of us at the dinner, Emilio, Chandran Kukathas, Stephen Macedo, Andrew Melnyk, and I. Our guest was in a very good mood and told us a lot about his life and works.

For example, Hayek recalled that at a meeting with Pope John Paul II (on 22 December 1980) he had used the word ‘superstitions’ about certain ideas which might be useful, but which were neither analytically nor empirically true. When he noticed that the holy father was not very happy with his choice of words, he gently suggested that perhaps ‘symbolic truths’ would be more appropriate. Pope John Paul immediately agreed and seemed quite pleased. Although himself an agnostic, Hayek always thought that the classical liberal movement should regard the christian churches as allies. He knew that they had been almost the only centres of resistance to European totalitarianism in the period of what we could call ‘the thirty years war’ from 1914 to 1945. During our conversation, it came out that Hayek was not sympathetic to ‘liberation theology’, then much in vogue in Latin America. ‘Paradoxically, liberation can be the opposite of liberty. It can indeed destroy liberty. We should not liberate ourselves from our liberal heritage, for example, or the rule of law,’ Hayek said.

Hayek told us that he had personally met four American presidents. The first one, unbelievably, was Calvin Coolidge in 1923. Hayek was then in America as the research assistant of an economics professor, and when the American Economic Association held its general meeting in Washington DC, it was small enough that the President could invite all the participants to a reception in the White House (on 27 December 1923). The second president Hayek met was Herbert Hoover but that was long after he had left office. During John F. Kennedy’s presidency he was once invited to the White House and again once by Ronald Reagan. ‘The interesting contrast between them,’ Hayek told us, ‘was that Kennedy seemed much less authentic than the professional actor Reagan. Kennedy pretended to have read several books of mine which of course he had not done, whereas Reagan told me that he had read one of my books, “The Road to Serfdom,” and that he had liked it a lot. Reagan had also been influenced by my old mentor Mises and by that brilliant journalist Frederic Bastiat.’ (The meeting with Reagan took place on 17 November 1983.)

MG 2859 scaled

Thatcher and the Queen

It was obvious that Hayek admired Margaret Thatcher who had become the Prime Minister of the United Kingdom in May 1979. She had been much influenced by Hayek. At the Ritz, Hayek told us that a few months after she took office she heard that he would be in London for a few days, and she therefore invited him to lunch at 10 Downing Street (on 17 September 1979). She greeted him at the entrance with the words: ‘Professor Hayek, I know precisely what you are going to say. You are going to say that I have not done enough. And you are absolutely right.’ Chuckling, Hayek said that it had been difficult for him to be very critical of her after this greeting. He was however rather scathing about her main opponents in the Conservative Party. He said that they were under an illusion created by John Stuart Mill that there was a crucial difference between the production and distribution of wealth and that the laws applying to one of these activities did not necessarily apply to the other one. Thus, they believed that income redistribution would not affect production much. In this they were wrong, Hayek argued, since income distribution offered guidance to us on the channels in which we should direct our efforts and energies.

Hayek also greatly appreciated another famous English woman, Queen Elizabeth the Second. He had in 1984 been made Companion of Honour, on Thatcher’s recommendation, and he received this award at an audience with the Queen at Buckingham Palace (on 16 June 1984). ‘I had not thought much of the Queen one way or another before. But I was pleasantly surprised. She was very well-informed and quite impressive. She performed her duties impeccably,’ he told us. Later the same day his English friends gave a dinner for him at the Institute of Economic Affairs which had tirelessly been promoting his ideas for decades, and he said that this had been the happiest day of his life. He was an Englishman by choice, not chance, although he always retained his Austrian roots.

MG 2690 scaled

‘The City of My Dreams’

Although Hayek was a British citizen, he lived with his second wife in Freiburg in Germany. He told us that the two German politicians whom he regarded as the ablest ones at present were Otto von Lambsdorff from the Free Democrats and Franz Josef Strauss from the Bavarian Christian Social Union. But they were quite hostile to each other. ‘It is a pity that the two of them cannot work together. They would have made a formidable team,’ Hayek said. Stephen Macedo asked him what he thought of the military junta in Chile. ‘The economic policies pursued in Chile have been quite sensible and indeed very successful,’ Hayek replied. ‘We have to make a distinction between authoritarianism and totalitarianism. The regime in Chile is certainly authoritarian, but it is not totalitarian. The main difference is that authoritarian is reversible, but totalitarianism may be almost irreversible, because a totalitarian regime destroys, or tries to destroy, all the ties and attachments and traditions which we broadly call civil society, and thus it eliminates most or almost all of its potential rivals.’

Hayek drank Burgundy which he said was his favourite branch of wine. At the close of the dinner, a group of musicians who had been circulating in the dining room playing at various tables came to our table and asked us whether we had any special melody which we wanted them to play. ‘Play the City of My Dreams,’ one of us whispered to them. When they started playing, Hayek immediately recognised the tune, beamed, and started to hum the song in German. ‘Mein Herz und mein Sinn schwärmt stets nur für Wien …’ It is an intriguing fact that now, thirty-seven years later, we should be celebrating the Hayek award here in Vienna, with a wonderful view over the whole city, Hayek’s city of dreams.

MG 2695 scaled

Liberty Fund

Indeed, sometimes dreams come true, as can be seen in the case of Liberty Fund in Indianapolis. This venerable institution was established in 1960 by a successful local businessman, Pierre F. Goodrich, an avid reader of classical literature as well as a passionate believer in liberty as the sweetest, and healthiest, fruit of Western civilisation. Liberty Fund is unique as an institution in that its focus is not on short-term policies, but rather on the conservative-liberal political tradition of the West, in a broad sense. It regularly holds colloquia which engage in what could be called Socratic dialogues, without any preset conclusions, and it publishes classical political texts in accessible formats, both on paper and online, including the collected works of Hayek, Ludwig von Mises, James M. Buchanan, Adam Smith, and John Stuart Mill. Dr. Emilio Pacheco has worked for Liberty Fund since 1991, as President from 2016 to 2020, and now as Senior Vice President and Pierre F. Goodrich Resident Scholar; and he has made a significant contribution to the remarkable activities of this institution.

I still remember how intellectually stimulating my two first Liberty Fund colloquia were in Oxford in the early 1980s when I had the chance to exchange ideas and arguments with such distinguished scholars as James M. Buchanan, Robert Nozick, and David Friedman. I can also personally testify to the impact and usefulness of the publishing activities of Liberty Fund: It helped me a lot when I was writing my recent book in two volumes about twenty-four conservative-liberal thinkers that Liberty Fund had made many of their books available online, by Hume, Burke, Bastiat, Tocqueville, Spencer, Sumner, Oakeshott and many others. Goodrich had even anticipated my own discovery of Icelandic chronicler Snorri Sturluson as a pioneer of classical liberal thought: Sturluson was on Goodrich’s list of thinkers who had contributed to our understanding of what it means to be free and responsible individuals, as visitors to the Goodrich Seminar Room at Wabash College can see for themselves.

In the same way as monasteries were sanctuaries for scholars in the Middle Ages, Liberty Fund has been a sanctuary for conservatives and classical liberals since its foundation, but more than that: it has been an inspiring forum for the discussion and development of conservative-liberal ideas. Emilio Pacheco and his colleagues at Liberty Fund well illustrate the old fact which Hayek used to stress that in the long run ideas are more powerful than special interests, that the pen is mightier than the sword.

Watch the recording of Prof. Gissurarson’s speech:

For privacy reasons YouTube needs your permission to be loaded.
I Accept

Author

Die Meinungen, die hier auf hayek-institut.at veröffentlicht wurden, entsprechen nicht notwendigerweise jenen des Hayek Instituts.

Gefällt Ihnen der Artikel?

Das freut uns! Bitte unterstützen Sie uns, wenn Sie mehr solcher Artikel lesen möchten:

Das interessiert Sie vielleicht auch:

Diesen Artikel teilen!

Jetzt zum Newsletter anmelden!